Thursday, December 21, 2017

Apple Admittedly Slows Older iPhones to ‘Protect Electronic Components’

Surprise: Apple iPhone performance slows as the device (and its battery) ages.

The struggle is real for iFans who, like clockwork, see a decline in their smartphone or tablet's efficiency after about a year of use.

Conspiracy theorists claim it's Cupertino's way of encouraging folks to upgrade their handset for the latest and greatest version. But, according to Apple, it's actually the battery's fault.

In a statement published by TechCrunch, the company admitted that it deliberately slows older iPhones to prevent damage:

"Our goal is to deliver the best experience for customers, which includes overall performance and prolonging the life of their devices. Lithium-ion batteries become less capable of supplying peak current demands when in cold conditions, have a low battery charge, or as they age over time, which can result in the device unexpectedly shutting down to protect its electronic components.

"Last year, we released a feature for iPhone 6, iPhone 6s, and iPhone SE to smooth out the instantaneous peaks only when needed to prevent the device from unexpectedly shutting down during these conditions. We've now extended that feature to iPhone 7 with iOS 11.2, and plan to add support for other products in the future."

The news broke this week after a recent Reddit post sparked discussion about the long-standing problem, addressed via benchmark tests by Primate Labs' John Poole.

"While we expect battery capacity to decrease as batteries age, we expect processor performance to stay the same," Poole wrote in a Monday blog post. "However, users with older iPhones with lower-than-expected Geekbench 4 scores have reported that replacing the battery increases their score (as well as the performance of the phone). What's going on here?"

What's going on—as Apple confirmed—is that the tech titan added power management to limit functionality once the battery condition declines past a certain point.

As TechCrunch pointed out, it's not just age that can negatively affect the power unit: excessive heat (whether from the sun or overuse) will also cripple a battery.

But before you start sending angry tweets to Apple, remember that this is the fault of lithium-ion chemistry, not Cupertino.

Which is, in large part, why graphene has gained such attention among battery manufacturers with the allotrope's top-notch physical and chemical stability. Graphene is 100 times more efficient than copper in conducting electricity and boasts electron mobility 140 times faster than silicon.

Let us know what you like about Geek by taking our survey.


Source: Apple Admittedly Slows Older iPhones to 'Protect Electronic Components'

Wednesday, December 20, 2017

CanPay: Solving Pot’s Payments Problem

Share

Share

Share

Share

Print

Email

https://www.pymnts.com/wp-content/uploads/2017/12/12.19_Matchmakers_DustinEide_Final.mp3

Pot has a payments problem.

Cannabis' status as a schedule-one narcotic means the federally chartered banks, the card networks and the traditional payments ecosystem have made it clear that they'd like to steer clear. In turn, that means digital payment methods of all kinds have largely been a no-go, making pot a $7 billion cash industry in 2016.

That's a situation that's untenable for a variety of reasons, Dustin Eide, CEO of CanPay, told Karen Webster in this week's edition of Matchmakers. Cash, especially that much of it, is an insecure, cumbersome, friction-filled currency – not to mention physically unclean, hard to keep track of, easy to miscount (and steal) and all around a hassle for businesses in regulated states that want to sell pot to patients and customers. It also means that dispensary owners, their customers, regulators on the state and local level and pretty much everyone in any state with a legal cannabis industry have a reason to want to de-cash the system as much as possible.

But, because of cannabis' legally complicated status, the traditional payments elixir of plastic cards or digital wallets has remained elusive.

Eide, a payments veteran himself, made it his business to solve what many consider to be an intractable payments problem.

"When we really decided to take on this problem, the first thing we did was to dig into what was purportedly available in the industry," Eide said. "We realized that digitizing payments for the legal purchase of cannabis was three layers more complicated than even normal payments backend stuff."

And, he added, there was a dearth of compliant, transparent solutions in the marketplace.

Eide and the CanPay team created the first debit-based, digital payments solution for the cannabis industry, built on a network of compliant financial institutions.

The Power Of Transparency

The Cole Memo, issued in 2013 by the Department of Justice, lays out the guidelines under which financial institutions can offer compliant financial services (like bank accounts) to businesses operating dispensaries in states where it is legal to sell medicinal and/or recreational marijuana.

As Eide noted, there is not an abundant number of Cole-compliant financial institutions operating in the U.S. – in fact, there are fewer than two dozen. Those few work hard to be very transparent about their services with regulators, but do not heavily market them otherwise, "because they can quickly be overwhelmed with requests for service," Eide explained.

But they do exist – and CanPay has made it easy for them to become part of an integrated, interoperable, secure payments network into which dispensary business can lawfully be paid using a digital method of payment – and not cash.

Eide said that although it may sound simple, it's actually a "big deal" given the lack of transparency associated with some digital payment solutions. In some cases, Eide noted, those solutions were either surreptitiously using the card networks by not making clear the businesses' actual intent, or by using an intermediary, like a gift card or cryptocurrency, to mask the purchase of cannabis.

CanPay, Eide said, is willing to take the card networks and national issuers seriously when they say they don't want to have anything to do with this industry – and that trying to leverage "tricky" solutions that just mask the payments problem is increasingly going out of fashion in the industry.

"Dispensary owners especially want to normalize their businesses," Eide said. "When you order from a restaurant, the name of that restaurant appears on the bill. There is a level of legitimacy that comes with transparency – and we see businesses that would rather use a solution that doesn't require them to do business under one name and financial transactions under another."

How It Works

The challenge of building a network of compliant banks was to first find a payments system that the financial institutions and regulators would be comfortable with. For CanPay, that was the ACH network. Then came a massive amount of work to devise a framework in which dispensaries would be permitted to accept CanPay as a method of payment.

The solution, Eide told Webster, was that any dispensary that wanted to use CanPay had to be enrolled as a customer with Cole-compliant financial institutions in their network, and therefore vetted by that institution.

Once CanPay has confirmation from their institution that they are a customer, they verify their licenses to ensure that everything is up to date and the business is who and what they say they are.

CanPay consumers have the option to link their checking accounts to their CanPay accounts via an app that is available on the web or by creating an account on the CanPay website.

Once the app is installed, a CanPay customer can log in at any accepting dispensary in the U.S. and initiate a payment from her checking account, which triggers a single-use pin that generates no identifying data and is only live for 30 minutes. Dispensaries have tablets that enable the software to process the payment.

"Once the merchant has the PIN, it is just like running a debit or credit card payment," noted Eide. The customer gets a payment-approved notice in the app, and they can walk away with their product.

Eide also noted that while the service is tablet-based today, they have been in talks with point-of-sale companies that are also focused on the cannabis industry, and they expect to see some integrations with the CanPay API in the near term.

The Changing Marketplace

Cannabis sales, Eide noted, are a complex problem to solve. In his opinion, "it is probably the most complicated payments challenge that I could have hoped to have found."

But, he said, as their integration in the state of Hawaii recently proved, it is complexity surrounding the ecosystem of cannabis that needs solving.

"Hawaii is a unique set of issues because it is an island state, where having massive cash pools because of the medical cannabis industry is a huge issue. You have large numbers of patients with cash in their pockets in concentrated locations, which creates a lot of targets. The logistics of moving money becomes a lot more complicated when you are talking about places with one road in and out: You have security flashpoints. Plus, you have to move this money on and off the island itself."

That created a unique set of pressures that brought the governor, the banking commissioner, the dispensaries and the financial institutions to the table to get a solution for digital payments up and running.

And because there was that widespread support, Eide noted, they were able to offer statewide cashless payments to Hawaiian dispensaries within eight months of starting the project.

The issues in the rest of the cannabis legal world may not be quite as stark, he told Webster – but as the annual value of the industry grows past $20 billion and even $50 billion a year, the idea of trying to manage it all in cash will become every bit as untenable in the contiguous United States as it became in Hawaii.

The cannabis industry wants digital payments – and the customers who use it are equally incented to use them.

Share

Share

Share

Share

Print

Email


Source: CanPay: Solving Pot's Payments Problem

Tuesday, December 19, 2017

4 Ways To Effectively Incorporate Technology Into Your Small Business

(Photo Credit: Thinkstock)

 Technology is the backbone of a successful 21st century small business. It allows small business owners to check email, monitor progress of jobs, and connect with clients outside the office and office hours. It's this flexibility that builds strong client relationships and business connections. The bottom line is bringing innovation to the client through following industry trends.

The tools to attain this level of client satisfaction varies from industry to industry, though the constants are a smartphone, tablet and a laptop computer. The business side of every small business, from an artist to a media company, creates its foundation on technology, innovation and the ability to deliver an end product.

 Business Process Automation

Business process automation (BPA) is advantageous to internal processes, marketing and product production. With internal processes, it streamlines lines of communications between departments and maintains consistency. This creates a business atmosphere that is easier to manage, complete tasks and make deadlines. The increase in efficiency creates a stronger bottom-line for businesses.

Marketing tasks can be automated. These require an expert to monitor, to maintain the business' branding and to keep a strong focus on company goals. Targeting intended audiences, this streamlines the process of reaching new and existing clients. There are many industry specific software options that can streamline business processes through automation. Automation allows a business to bid for larger jobs, and remain competitive. The bottom line for all small businesses is efficiency. Technology through automated processes allows a small business to operate more efficiently and lower operating costs.

 Using the correct technology

The technology that works best for most small businesses is a cell phone and laptop computer. With these two pieces of equipment, a business can be run from anywhere, including internationally. It is vital to stay up-to-date with equipment and software to remain competitive. To be connected means an increased ability to increase clientele and profits.

International travel requires a different set of technology needs. Besides the power adapter to keep equipment charges, there is a different line of software programs to access for use. Some of the best programs are international wireless Hotspot, Ring Central, Zoom Meeting, Join Me and Infusion Soft.

 Keys to successful technology use

One of the keys to a successful business is the ability to analyze the marketplace and then follow the trends. It's important to stay up-to-date with the demands of the marketplace and be able to address a client's current needs. Technology allows a small business to see and adapt to new trends, and stay competitive. A strong business plan and ethics combined with the smart use of technology create a strong marketplace presence. These include the ability to take risks, to have a problem-solving mindset and keeping the organization under a goal-oriented philosophy.

 Staying competitive

Technology allows small businesses to maintain a consistent product. It gives the ability to share changes quicker and keep records of these changes. It allows a business to grow quicker, maintain consistency and provides better lines of communication between departments. Social media platforms also help by adding visibility for a small business. LinkedIn is very popular for businesses, as it offers a place to promote a business, product or service. In addition, it gives businesses an opportunity to expand through the large pool of employment seeking individuals on the service. 

 This article was written by Karen Ulvestad for Small Business Pulse 


Source: 4 Ways To Effectively Incorporate Technology Into Your Small Business

Saturday, December 16, 2017

Google, Facebook, Amazon: Our Digital Overlords

Editor's note: This piece appears in the December 18, 2017, print issue of National Review.

The Left's cause du jour is "monopolies." Well, not monopolies, necessarily. The new line is that it's inherently problematic when even as many as three or four companies dominate an industry, and that the government needs to take action, pronto.

This is an overreaction, as Robert D. Atkinson and Michael Lind have explained in this space ("The Neo-Brandeisian Attack on Big Business," October 2, 2017). In many cases it's actually better, for workers and consumers alike, to have a few big, highly efficient companies duking it out with one another than to have hundreds of tiny ones fumbling around in the marketplace.

But there are real monopolies in this country, and three of them — Alphabet (i.e., Google), Amazon, and Facebook — control much of our online life. They are already showing anti-competitive tendencies, as well as censoring speech, and yet there is no perfect response to such practices. These firms could do great damage if left unchecked — but then again, their market dominance might not be as secure as it seems.

It's not time to smash these companies to pieces. But it just might be time to rein in some of their most egregious practices.

Traditionally, the case against monopolies has gone something like this. In a competitive market, companies must charge the lowest price they profitably can or else lose out to their rivals. If a company were to, say, arbitrarily hike its prices by half, the vast majority of its customers would simply head elsewhere. By contrast, if there isn't much competition to speak of, a company can charge whatever the market will bear. It might hike its prices by half and lose only a quarter of its sales — pulling in more revenue for less effort — because customers won't have an alternative. Their only options are to pay the new price or go without the product entirely.

This problem might then compound as the monopolist leverages its power. A company might take the extra money it makes from a monopoly on one product and use it to secure monopolies on other products — losing money at first as it sells items below cost to drive out the competition, then hiking prices. Or it might pursue "vertical integration"; the company that owns all the oil refineries might buy up the pipelines and railroad tankers as well, monopolizing the entire chain of businesses through which consumers gain access to a product. And if a monopolist doesn't outright take over those related industries, it can use its monopoly clout to extract concessions from the other businesses it deals with, as well as from workers.

It's not illegal simply to have a monopoly so long as it was established through legal means, but it is illegal to abuse monopoly power in various ways. And concerns about abuse cut across ideological lines. Liberals, naturally, will jump at any chance to hammer big companies. And conservatives are keenly aware that capitalism works so well thanks to the magic of competition — and cannot work without it.

Judge Learned Hand once wrote that a 90 percent market share "is enough to constitute a monopoly; it is doubtful whether sixty or sixty-four percent would be enough; and certainly thirty-three percent is not." In practice, courts put the cutoff somewhere between 70 and 80 percent, a range in which the company is about two to four times the size of all its competitors put together.

The applicability of traditional thinking about monopolies is limited when it comes to the Godzillas of tech.

The applicability of traditional thinking about monopolies is limited, however, when it comes to the Godzillas of tech. Google and Facebook, which monopolize online search (91 percent market share) and mobile social media (77 percent) respectively, don't charge the end users of those products a cent. And while Amazon has a monopoly, or at least a near-monopoly, over e-book sales (70 percent), it doesn't control the broader market of online retail, which itself is less than one-tenth of total retail in the U.S. Moreover, far from hiking prices, Amazon has gone out of its way to keep them low, earning little to no profit each year and focusing its efforts on growth. And to cap it all off, while these companies' competitors may be tiny, all a customer has to do is type in a different Web address to access them. So what's the problem?

Let's take a brief look at some of these companies' most controversial actions — and the actions they have the power to take even if they haven't yet.

Here's one that got Google clobbered with a $2.7 billion fine from the European Union, and it has to do with what happens when someone, well, "googles" the name of a product. Years ago, such a search would turn up some links to "comparison shopping" websites — places users could go to compare prices at different retailers. Recently, though, comparison-shopping sites have shown up on page four of the results, at best.

Why might that be? Because Google decided that what its users really wanted to do was comparison-shop among retailers who pay Google. Today, anyone searching the name of a product is first shown a selection of "sponsored" offerings, complete with pictures and prices of specific products. Below that, where the normal search results begin, there are direct links to retailers (I recently got a Home Depot link in a search for "lawnmower") but no links to other price-comparison options. Portions of a report inadvertently leaked by the Federal Trade Commission here in the U.S. showed that Google had deliberately rigged its algorithm to penalize competing sites — leveraging its monopoly over Web search to take other companies' business. There is also some evidence that this practice pushed up prices: The ad spots are allocated via auction, the costs of which participating retailers have to cover, and as a result the products the search engine highlights are often more expensi ve than what a consumer could find if he compared prices a different way.

There's more where that came from. The EU is also investigating Google with regard to Android, an operating system for smartphones. Much the way Google search is free to the end user, Android is free for companies that make smartphones. And as much as one hears about each new version of the iPhone (which runs Apple's own iOS), Android is installed on more than 80 percent of the smartphones sold today. The flipside of free is that there are strings attached: Smartphone companies must sell their phones with Google's own apps pre-installed, "nudging" the user to use Google products across the board. (On my own Android phone, Google Play Movies & TV is mysteriously considered a "system app" and cannot be uninstalled.) This is remarkably similar to the practice that got Microsoft in hot water two decades ago, when it sold Windows, its monopoly operating system, with its own Internet browser set up as the default, doing great damage to its rival Netscape.

Back in 2013, U.S. regulators put an end to two other anti-competitive practices at Google. In addition to selling ads on its own products, Google runs AdSense, which places ads on any website that wants to participate and passes along some of the revenue; the company agreed to lift restrictions it had placed on companies that used other ad services in addition to AdSense. It also apparently needed to be told it couldn't "scrape" user reviews from websites such as Yelp (through which people can weigh in on local restaurants and other businesses) and include those reviews on its own sites.

Google isn't always hyper-competent when it executes these kinds of anti-competitive moves, however. In 2011 it had a meeting at Forbes in which it told the media company it would receive better search rankings if its articles included a button that readers could click to share a link on Google Plus, a social-media site. Apparently a journalist invited to the meeting wasn't told it was confidential and wrote a piece about the practice — and despite the effort to manhandle press outlets that heavily rely on Google's search engine for traffic, hardly anyone uses Google Plus today.

Of the three tech giants against which allegations of "monopolization" are often made, Amazon is the most interesting, as it controls less than half of the online-retail market. In a celebrated Yale Law Journal article that serves as an excellent catalogue of everything Amazon has done wrong, Lina M. Khan argued at length that the company essentially breaks the mold; regulators' current criteria for anti-competitive behavior just don't capture what the company has been up to. And indeed, she documents many troubling practices.

The foundation of Amazon's business strategy, oddly enough, is an unwillingness to make a profit. The company has wound up in the black more often in recent years, but it consistently ran losses for much of its history, and generally speaking it keeps prices low and spends any extra revenue on efforts to grow. Its shareholders have been content to watch their stock gain value as the company gets bigger rather than receiving a share of any profits. And grow the company has. It doesn't just sell stuff online; it also serves as a marketplace for other sellers, provides cloud-computing services, produces movies and TV shows, and manages a distribution chain. It now owns Whole Foods, whose stores could soon serve as distribution hubs.

In other words, Amazon has tons of money rolling in, and shareholders aren't clamoring to see any of it, so losses are acceptable so long as they serve the purpose of growth. One thing this means is that when Amazon wants to obliterate the competition in a specific market niche, it can sell below cost like an old-fashioned monopolist. That is how it established a monopoly in e-books: It lost money on bestselling titles, and probably on the Kindle e-reader device as well. Regulators declined to step in, noting that Amazon's e-book sales were profitable overall, even if the company was losing money on bestsellers in particular. (Incredibly, they did step in when Apple and five of the six major publishers established "agency pricing" for the iBookstore, by which books' publishers would set whatever price they wanted on each title and Apple would take 30 percent. At the time this happened, Amazon controlled 90 percent of the e-book market.)

Once Amazon had gained such enormous market share, it had the ability to boss book publishers around. The maker of a product cannot afford to be kept away from a majority of its potential customers, and this is especially true when the monopolist ties its customers to itself through a device such as the Kindle, which gives the user direct access to the Amazon store and automatically downloads any Amazon e-books he purchases from other devices as well. (Many Kindle users don't even know it's possible to put non-Amazon files on the device, which is not too difficult for the tech-savvy but entails a somewhat obscure process.) Amazon is famous for yanking publishers' catalogues from its store during negotiations.

When the smaller company rebuffed the bigger one's attempt to purchase it, Amazon slashed prices on baby products by up to 30 percent.

Quidsi, which operated several retail websites, including Diapers.com, also got a taste of what it means to go up against Amazon. When the smaller company rebuffed the bigger one's attempt to purchase it, Amazon slashed prices on baby products by up to 30 percent. It set up digital "bots" that monitored prices on Diapers.com and automatically undercut them every time they changed, and it started services that gave regular baby-products customers even deeper discounts. Quidsi alleged that the strategy would cause Amazon to lose $100 million over three months, losses a smaller company could not sustain. Quidsi finally sold to Amazon, which responded to its new freedom from competition by raising prices and scaling back discounts.

This isn't "creative destruction"; Amazon didn't come up with a better way to sell people diapers. It just kept sustaining losses until its smaller competitor gave up.

Then there's the fact that, in addition to selling products itself, Amazon serves as a platform for other sellers — many product pages show multiple offers, and some products are available only through non-Amazon sellers. In a sense this is admirably pro-competitive, as Amazon is giving smaller sellers a way to reach its huge user base (for a fee). But there's a downside for other companies that succeed through Amazon's infrastructure: Amazon sees all their sales data, meaning the entire third-party Amazon marketplace is basically a big test lab for Amazon proper. If another company's product succeeds, Amazon can in short order start offering a similar product itself at the same price (or less). Some Amazon sellers have accused the company of doing just that, even with rather distinctive products such as pillows modeled after football mascots.

There are two other threats the tech monopolies pose that are worth briefly discussing: They are in a good position to maintain their dominance, and their dominance brings with it an extraordinary power to shape public discourse.

It's well known that older companies gradually lose their mojo, making them vulnerable to ambitious start-ups. Recently I was surprised to learn, for example, that a higher percentage of adolescents use Instagram (a photo-centric social-media site) than use Facebook. Then I learned that Facebook has owned Instagram since 2012. Facebook has also persistently tried to buy Snapchat, another photo app popular with teens.

Acquisition is a common way for tech monopolies to entrench their position, and it normally doesn't require the sort of strong-arm tactics that Amazon employed against Quidsi. Alphabet, Google's parent corporation, has purchased more than 200 companies over its lifespan, integrating its purchases into its various offerings. It's hardly any surprise that by one analysis, from Google critic Scott Cleland, the company leads in 13 of the Internet's 14 key "commercial web functions of the Internet data economy," the exception being social media: "data collection, search, tracking-analytics, digital advertising, mobile, video, location, browser, Internet Infrastructure, consumer-Internet of Things, Apps store, translation, & email."

Some major tech products, including Google Docs, were acquired at the start rather than developed in-house. "Initial public offerings" of start-up companies have declined in recent years, perhaps in part because so many companies work toward the goal of being bought up by a giant rather than succeeding on their own.

The potential for political meddling is substantial and troubling when a single company controls a key way that Americans across the political spectrum find their information.

And today, an incredible proportion of the information driving public discourse runs through Google and Facebook. To be clear, this does not pose any sort of First Amendment issue — these are private companies, and the Constitution does not dictate how they program their search algorithms or decide which stories appear on users' news feeds. But the potential for political meddling is substantial and troubling when a single company controls a key way that Americans across the political spectrum find their information.

Russian bots famously were designed to spread breathless "fake news" on Facebook in the runup to the 2016 election, a problem the company is now looking to fix. Last year, some former Facebook employees told the tech site Gizmodo that they had, at their superiors' request, deliberately kept conservative topics such as the annual CPAC gathering out of Facebook's "Trending Topics" section. Google's YouTube has banned or "demonetized" (refused to run ads on, depriving the creators of revenue) videos created by various right-wing figures, including Michelle Malkin. One study suggested that if Google deliberately tweaked search results to favor a candidate, it could influence about 2 percent of votes, enough to sway close elections.

Google has also made itself a powerful player in the D.C. think-tank world, funding a variety of institutions on the right and left alike. The company has never hidden these efforts, and they fall well within its rights, but they burst into the public consciousness earlier this year when the left-leaning New America Foundation parted ways with its Open Markets Institute. The latter's head, Barry Lynn, had praised the aforementioned EU ruling against Google — which generously funded other projects at New America.

So what's the solution? The most draconian option would be to just start busting up these companies. Last year in Washington Monthly, Lynn and his New America colleague Phillip Longman called for the government to "break up Amazon, Facebook, Google, Comcast, and any other essential network monopoly by banning them from owning companies that depend on their services." In the blog post that presaged his departure from New America, Lynn called on U.S. regulators to "cleanly separate ownership of the network from ownership of the products and services sold on that network, as they did in the original Microsoft case of the late 1990s." (Before the ultimate settlement, a court ruling would have broken up the maker of Windows.)

The Microsoft example is instructive: No one is very afraid of the company these days even though the government failed to break it up, opting instead to gently restrict its business practices. The company is doing well financially, largely owing to its cloud-computing services, but the monopoly worries have faded: PC sales have dropped off thanks to the rise of smartphones and tablets, an attempt to put Windows on mobile phones flopped, Microsoft's Internet browsers are just a fifth of the market, and its search engine is an afterthought. It's perfectly conceivable that today's seemingly secure tech monopolies will lose their grip over time too.

But gentler approaches are available to address more immediate problems, starting with the EU's strategy for comparison-shopping sites, which in that same post Lynn described as "requiring that Google give equal treatment to rival services instead of privileging its own." One could also imagine requiring companies such as Amazon to keep other companies' sales data private, though that would be difficult to enforce, or banning companies that reach a certain market share from selling below cost, especially in a concentrated effort to destroy a competitor. (Indeed, this is already illegal in some circumstances, though the law is rarely enforced.) In a similar vein, Jonathan Taplin, author of Move Fast and Break Things, has suggested stopping the tech monopolies from acquiring still more small ventures, requiring them to operate as public utilities (such as by licensing their patents for a set fee), and mandating that they take greater steps to prevent intellectual-property in fringement on their networks.

If these companies are going to control a huge part of our lives without facing competition, they can do a better job of respecting others' rights.

Regarding this last item, companies such as Google and Facebook are currently given "safe harbor" under a law passed 20 years ago, when the Internet was a fledgling technology in need of special legal protections — essentially meaning they can't be held liable for their users' piracy, or for pointing users to pirated material in search results, unless a creator has specifically requested the removal of an infringing post or link. There are limits to how much we can expect search engines and social networks to fight piracy, of course, even if they're huge monopolies. But the first Google result for "nirvana smells like teen spirit mp3" should not be a bare-bones website that helps users download songs for free from mysterious, unnamed sources rather than hosting the files itself, as it was when I searched those words recently. If these companies are going to control a huge part of our lives without facing competition, they can do a better job of respecting others' rights.

Speaking of which, Jeremy Carl of Stanford's Hoover Institution has suggested basically applying the First Amendment to these companies. Google (and its YouTube), Facebook (and its Instagram), and any future monopolies could be prohibited from banning, censoring, or demonetizing any speech that is legal. They would act as common carriers available to all.

Some mix of the above measures might preserve a competitive marketplace without a heavy-handed government assault on private businesses. But as yet, it's unclear how the Trump administration will approach the issue of tech monopolies and antitrust law more generally, and to what extent Congress is open to these ideas.

The administration has recently sued to block the merger of AT&T and Time Warner, an aggressive move but one that (ostensibly) relies on age-old antitrust concerns. It's an example of "vertical integration" between two companies that are large but not monopolies: Time Warner owns television networks such as HBO and TNT, while AT&T distributes those networks through products such as DirecTV. In theory, the two combined could benefit from charging AT&T's competitors artificially high rates for Time Warner's content, harming consumers in the process. The other possible rationale is that Trump is merely trying to punish Time Warner, which owns his media archenemy, CNN.

Either way, the suit doesn't provide much of a signal as to how the administration sees Google. But there's certainly a populist angle to keeping a check on enormous companies when no competitors are around to do so — and a conservative angle to ensuring that competition flourishes online.

READ MORE:On Amazon and the Tech MonopoliesSilicon Valley Billionaires Are the New Robber BaronsHow to Break Silicon Valley's Anti-Free-Speech Monopoly

— Robert VerBruggen is a deputy managing editor of National Review.


Source: Google, Facebook, Amazon: Our Digital Overlords

Thursday, December 14, 2017

Hundreds of HP Laptops, Tablets Found with Pre-Installed Keylogger

A security researcher has found that hundreds of different models of HP notebooks, tablets and other devices include a keylogger that could track and record every keystroke a user makes. Linked to touchpad drivers made by Synaptics, the keylogger is disabled by default and can be fixed with security patches released by HP last month.

The keylogger was discovered by security researcher Michael Myng, who publicly disclosed his findings in a blog post Thursday. In his post, Myng said that he messaged HP about his discovery and the company responded quickly by confirming the issue and releasing a software update to resolve the problem.

HP said neither it nor Synaptics "has access to customer data as a result of this issue." However, after a registry change, the keylogger could enable a malicious actor to monitor a user's keyboard activity.

More than 450 Affected Devices

Writing under the handle "ZwClose," Myng said he discovered the keylogger after an associate asked whether he could find a way to control the keyboard backlighting on an HP laptop. When he opened the keyboard driver SynTP.sys, Myng said he noticed "a few interesting strings," in particular, one that looked like a format string for a keylogger.

"I messaged HP about the finding," Myng said. "They replied terrificly [sic] fast, confirmed the presence of the keylogger (which actually was a debug trace) and released an update that removes the trace."

In a Nov. 7 security update, HP provided links to software patches for more than 450 products, including multiple models of the HP Notebook, HP EliteBook, HP Mobile Thin Client, HP ProBook, HP Spectre Pro and HP ZBook Mobile Workstation. The company said that affected users should install the appropriate update for their devices as soon as possible.

Second Keylogger Issue this Year

"A potential security vulnerability has been identified with certain versions of Synaptics touchpad drivers that impacts all Synaptics OEM partners," HP said in last month's security bulletin. "A party would need administrative privileges in order to take advantage of the vulnerability."

This isn't the first time such an issue has affected HP devices. In May, researchers with Switzerland-based security company Modzero reported finding a keylogging vulnerability in the Conexant audio drivers in HP laptops.

That problem, like the one reported by Myng, was blamed on debugging code that had been inadvertently left by developers. It also affected numerous models, including HP EliteBooks, ProBooks, and ZBooks.

In a statement acknowledging the May keylogger discovery, HP said it had "no access to customer data as a result of this issue. Our supplier partner developed software to test audio functionality prior to product launch and it should not have been included in the final shipped version."


Source: Hundreds of HP Laptops, Tablets Found with Pre-Installed Keylogger

Tuesday, December 12, 2017

Google, Facebook, Amazon: Our Digital Overlords

The Left's cause du jour is "monopolies." Well, not monopolies, necessarily. The new line is that it's inherently problematic when even as many as three or four companies dominate an industry, and that the government needs to take action, pronto.

This is an overreaction, as Robert D. Atkinson and Michael Lind have explained in this space ("The Neo-Brandeisian Attack on Big Business," October 2, 2017). In many cases it's actually better, for workers and consumers alike, to have a few big, highly efficient companies duking it out with one another than to have hundreds of tiny ones fumbling around in the marketplace.

But there are real monopolies in this country, and three of them — Alphabet (i.e., Google), Amazon, and Facebook — control much of our online life. They are already showing anti-competitive tendencies, as well as censoring speech, and yet there is no perfect response to such practices. These firms could do great damage if left unchecked — but then again, their market dominance might not be as secure as it seems.

It's not time to smash these companies to pieces. But it just might be time to rein in some of their most egregious practices.

Traditionally, the case against monopolies has gone something like this. In a competitive market, companies must charge the lowest price they profitably can or else lose out to their rivals. If a company were to, say, arbitrarily hike its prices by half, the vast majority of its customers would simply head elsewhere. By contrast, if there isn't much competition to speak of, a company can charge whatever the market will bear. It might hike its prices by half and lose only a quarter of its sales — pulling in more revenue for less effort — because customers won't have an alternative. Their only options are to pay the new price or go without the product entirely.

This problem might then compound as the monopolist leverages its power. A company might take the extra money it makes from a monopoly on one product and use it to secure monopolies on other products — losing money at first as it sells items below cost to drive out the competition, then hiking prices. Or it might pursue "vertical integration"; the company that owns all the oil refineries might buy up the pipelines and railroad tankers as well, monopolizing the entire chain of businesses through which consumers gain access to a product. And if a monopolist doesn't outright take over those related industries, it can use its monopoly clout to extract concessions from the other businesses it deals with, as well as from workers.

It's not illegal simply to have a monopoly so long as it was established through legal means, but it is illegal to abuse monopoly power in various ways. And concerns about abuse cut across ideological lines. Liberals, naturally, will jump at any chance to hammer big companies. And conservatives are keenly aware that capitalism works so well thanks to the magic of competition — and cannot work without it.

Judge Learned Hand once wrote that a 90 percent market share "is enough to constitute a monopoly; it is doubtful whether sixty or sixty-four percent would be enough; and certainly thirty-three percent is not." In practice, courts put the cutoff somewhere between 70 and 80 percent, a range in which the company is about two to four times the size of all its competitors put together.

The applicability of traditional thinking about monopolies is limited when it comes to the Godzillas of tech.

The applicability of traditional thinking about monopolies is limited, however, when it comes to the Godzillas of tech. Google and Facebook, which monopolize online search (91 percent market share) and mobile social media (77 percent) respectively, don't charge the end users of those products a cent. And while Amazon has a monopoly, or at least a near-monopoly, over e-book sales (70 percent), it doesn't control the broader market of online retail, which itself is less than one-tenth of total retail in the U.S. Moreover, far from hiking prices, Amazon has gone out of its way to keep them low, earning little to no profit each year and focusing its efforts on growth. And to cap it all off, while these companies' competitors may be tiny, all a customer has to do is type in a different Web address to access them. So what's the problem?

Let's take a brief look at some of these companies' most controversial actions — and the actions they have the power to take even if they haven't yet.

Here's one that got Google clobbered with a $2.7 billion fine from the European Union, and it has to do with what happens when someone, well, "googles" the name of a product. Years ago, such a search would turn up some links to "comparison shopping" websites — places users could go to compare prices at different retailers. Recently, though, comparison-shopping sites have shown up on page four of the results, at best.

Why might that be? Because Google decided that what its users really wanted to do was comparison-shop among retailers who pay Google. Today, anyone searching the name of a product is first shown a selection of "sponsored" offerings, complete with pictures and prices of specific products. Below that, where the normal search results begin, there are direct links to retailers (I recently got a Home Depot link in a search for "lawnmower") but no links to other price-comparison options. Portions of a report inadvertently leaked by the Federal Trade Commission here in the U.S. showed that Google had deliberately rigged its algorithm to penalize competing sites — leveraging its monopoly over Web search to take other companies' business. There is also some evidence that this practice pushed up prices: The ad spots are allocated via auction, the costs of which participating retailers have to cover, and as a result the products the search engine highlights are often more expensi ve than what a consumer could find if he compared prices a different way.

There's more where that came from. The EU is also investigating Google with regard to Android, an operating system for smartphones. Much the way Google search is free to the end user, Android is free for companies that make smartphones. And as much as one hears about each new version of the iPhone (which runs Apple's own iOS), Android is installed on more than 80 percent of the smartphones sold today. The flipside of free is that there are strings attached: Smartphone companies must sell their phones with Google's own apps pre-installed, "nudging" the user to use Google products across the board. (On my own Android phone, Google Play Movies & TV is mysteriously considered a "system app" and cannot be uninstalled.) This is remarkably similar to the practice that got Microsoft in hot water two decades ago, when it sold Windows, its monopoly operating system, with its own Internet browser set up as the default, doing great damage to its rival Netscape.

Back in 2013, U.S. regulators put an end to two other anti-competitive practices at Google. In addition to selling ads on its own products, Google runs AdSense, which places ads on any website that wants to participate and passes along some of the revenue; the company agreed to lift restrictions it had placed on companies that used other ad services in addition to AdSense. It also apparently needed to be told it couldn't "scrape" user reviews from websites such as Yelp (through which people can weigh in on local restaurants and other businesses) and include those reviews on its own sites.

Google isn't always hyper-competent when it executes these kinds of anti-competitive moves, however. In 2011 it had a meeting at Forbes in which it told the media company it would receive better search rankings if its articles included a button that readers could click to share a link on Google Plus, a social-media site. Apparently a journalist invited to the meeting wasn't told it was confidential and wrote a piece about the practice — and despite the effort to manhandle press outlets that heavily rely on Google's search engine for traffic, hardly anyone uses Google Plus today.

Of the three tech giants against which allegations of "monopolization" are often made, Amazon is the most interesting, as it controls less than half of the online-retail market. In a celebrated Yale Law Journal article that serves as an excellent catalogue of everything Amazon has done wrong, Lina M. Khan argued at length that the company essentially breaks the mold; regulators' current criteria for anti-competitive behavior just don't capture what the company has been up to. And indeed, she documents many troubling practices.

The foundation of Amazon's business strategy, oddly enough, is an unwillingness to make a profit. The company has wound up in the black more often in recent years, but it consistently ran losses for much of its history, and generally speaking it keeps prices low and spends any extra revenue on efforts to grow. Its shareholders have been content to watch their stock gain value as the company gets bigger rather than receiving a share of any profits. And grow the company has. It doesn't just sell stuff online; it also serves as a marketplace for other sellers, provides cloud-computing services, produces movies and TV shows, and manages a distribution chain. It now owns Whole Foods, whose stores could soon serve as distribution hubs.

In other words, Amazon has tons of money rolling in, and shareholders aren't clamoring to see any of it, so losses are acceptable so long as they serve the purpose of growth. One thing this means is that when Amazon wants to obliterate the competition in a specific market niche, it can sell below cost like an old-fashioned monopolist. That is how it established a monopoly in e-books: It lost money on bestselling titles, and probably on the Kindle e-reader device as well. Regulators declined to step in, noting that Amazon's e-book sales were profitable overall, even if the company was losing money on bestsellers in particular. (Incredibly, they did step in when Apple and five of the six major publishers established "agency pricing" for the iBookstore, by which books' publishers would set whatever price they wanted on each title and Apple would take 30 percent. At the time this happened, Amazon controlled 90 percent of the e-book market.)

Once Amazon had gained such enormous market share, it had the ability to boss book publishers around. The maker of a product cannot afford to be kept away from a majority of its potential customers, and this is especially true when the monopolist ties its customers to itself through a device such as the Kindle, which gives the user direct access to the Amazon store and automatically downloads any Amazon e-books he purchases from other devices as well. (Many Kindle users don't even know it's possible to put non-Amazon files on the device, which is not too difficult for the tech-savvy but entails a somewhat obscure process.) Amazon is famous for yanking publishers' catalogues from its store during negotiations.

When the smaller company rebuffed the bigger one's attempt to purchase it, Amazon slashed prices on baby products by up to 30 percent.

Quidsi, which operated several retail websites, including Diapers.com, also got a taste of what it means to go up against Amazon. When the smaller company rebuffed the bigger one's attempt to purchase it, Amazon slashed prices on baby products by up to 30 percent. It set up digital "bots" that monitored prices on Diapers.com and automatically undercut them every time they changed, and it started services that gave regular baby-products customers even deeper discounts. Quidsi alleged that the strategy would cause Amazon to lose $100 million over three months, losses a smaller company could not sustain. Quidsi finally sold to Amazon, which responded to its new freedom from competition by raising prices and scaling back discounts.

This isn't "creative destruction"; Amazon didn't come up with a better way to sell people diapers. It just kept sustaining losses until its smaller competitor gave up.

Then there's the fact that, in addition to selling products itself, Amazon serves as a platform for other sellers — many product pages show multiple offers, and some products are available only through non-Amazon sellers. In a sense this is admirably pro-competitive, as Amazon is giving smaller sellers a way to reach its huge user base (for a fee). But there's a downside for other companies that succeed through Amazon's infrastructure: Amazon sees all their sales data, meaning the entire third-party Amazon marketplace is basically a big test lab for Amazon proper. If another company's product succeeds, Amazon can in short order start offering a similar product itself at the same price (or less). Some Amazon sellers have accused the company of doing just that, even with rather distinctive products such as pillows modeled after football mascots.

There are two other threats the tech monopolies pose that are worth briefly discussing: They are in a good position to maintain their dominance, and their dominance brings with it an extraordinary power to shape public discourse.

It's well known that older companies gradually lose their mojo, making them vulnerable to ambitious start-ups. Recently I was surprised to learn, for example, that a higher percentage of adolescents use Instagram (a photo-centric social-media site) than use Facebook. Then I learned that Facebook has owned Instagram since 2012. Facebook has also persistently tried to buy Snapchat, another photo app popular with teens.

Acquisition is a common way for tech monopolies to entrench their position, and it normally doesn't require the sort of strong-arm tactics that Amazon employed against Quidsi. Alphabet, Google's parent corporation, has purchased more than 200 companies over its lifespan, integrating its purchases into its various offerings. It's hardly any surprise that by one analysis, from Google critic Scott Cleland, the company leads in 13 of the Internet's 14 key "commercial web functions of the Internet data economy," the exception being social media: "data collection, search, tracking-analytics, digital advertising, mobile, video, location, browser, Internet Infrastructure, consumer-Internet of Things, Apps store, translation, & email."

Some major tech products, including Google Docs, were acquired at the start rather than developed in-house. "Initial public offerings" of start-up companies have declined in recent years, perhaps in part because so many companies work toward the goal of being bought up by a giant rather than succeeding on their own.

The potential for political meddling is substantial and troubling when a single company controls a key way that Americans across the political spectrum find their information.

And today, an incredible proportion of the information driving public discourse runs through Google and Facebook. To be clear, this does not pose any sort of First Amendment issue — these are private companies, and the Constitution does not dictate how they program their search algorithms or decide which stories appear on users' news feeds. But the potential for political meddling is substantial and troubling when a single company controls a key way that Americans across the political spectrum find their information.

Russian bots famously were designed to spread breathless "fake news" on Facebook in the runup to the 2016 election, a problem the company is now looking to fix. Last year, some former Facebook employees told the tech site Gizmodo that they had, at their superiors' request, deliberately kept conservative topics such as the annual CPAC gathering out of Facebook's "Trending Topics" section. Google's YouTube has banned or "demonetized" (refused to run ads on, depriving the creators of revenue) videos created by various right-wing figures, including Michelle Malkin. One study suggested that if Google deliberately tweaked search results to favor a candidate, it could influence about 2 percent of votes, enough to sway close elections.

Google has also made itself a powerful player in the D.C. think-tank world, funding a variety of institutions on the right and left alike. The company has never hidden these efforts, and they fall well within its rights, but they burst into the public consciousness earlier this year when the left-leaning New America Foundation parted ways with its Open Markets Institute. The latter's head, Barry Lynn, had praised the aforementioned EU ruling against Google — which generously funded other projects at New America.

So what's the solution? The most draconian option would be to just start busting up these companies. Last year in Washington Monthly, Lynn and his New America colleague Phillip Longman called for the government to "break up Amazon, Facebook, Google, Comcast, and any other essential network monopoly by banning them from owning companies that depend on their services." In the blog post that presaged his departure from New America, Lynn called on U.S. regulators to "cleanly separate ownership of the network from ownership of the products and services sold on that network, as they did in the original Microsoft case of the late 1990s." (Before the ultimate settlement, a court ruling would have broken up the maker of Windows.)

The Microsoft example is instructive: No one is very afraid of the company these days even though the government failed to break it up, opting instead to gently restrict its business practices. The company is doing well financially, largely owing to its cloud-computing services, but the monopoly worries have faded: PC sales have dropped off thanks to the rise of smartphones and tablets, an attempt to put Windows on mobile phones flopped, Microsoft's Internet browsers are just a fifth of the market, and its search engine is an afterthought. It's perfectly conceivable that today's seemingly secure tech monopolies will lose their grip over time too.

But gentler approaches are available to address more immediate problems, starting with the EU's strategy for comparison-shopping sites, which in that same post Lynn described as "requiring that Google give equal treatment to rival services instead of privileging its own." One could also imagine requiring companies such as Amazon to keep other companies' sales data private, though that would be difficult to enforce, or banning companies that reach a certain market share from selling below cost, especially in a concentrated effort to destroy a competitor. (Indeed, this is already illegal in some circumstances, though the law is rarely enforced.) In a similar vein, Jonathan Taplin, author of Move Fast and Break Things, has suggested stopping the tech monopolies from acquiring still more small ventures, requiring them to operate as public utilities (such as by licensing their patents for a set fee), and mandating that they take greater steps to prevent intellectual-property in fringement on their networks.

If these companies are going to control a huge part of our lives without facing competition, they can do a better job of respecting others' rights.

Regarding this last item, companies such as Google and Facebook are currently given "safe harbor" under a law passed 20 years ago, when the Internet was a fledgling technology in need of special legal protections — essentially meaning they can't be held liable for their users' piracy, or for pointing users to pirated material in search results, unless a creator has specifically requested the removal of an infringing post or link. There are limits to how much we can expect search engines and social networks to fight piracy, of course, even if they're huge monopolies. But the first Google result for "nirvana smells like teen spirit mp3" should not be a bare-bones website that helps users download songs for free from mysterious, unnamed sources rather than hosting the files itself, as it was when I searched those words recently. If these companies are going to control a huge part of our lives without facing competition, they can do a better job of respecting others' rights.

Speaking of which, Jeremy Carl of Stanford's Hoover Institution has suggested basically applying the First Amendment to these companies. Google (and its YouTube), Facebook (and its Instagram), and any future monopolies could be prohibited from banning, censoring, or demonetizing any speech that is legal. They would act as common carriers available to all.

Some mix of the above measures might preserve a competitive marketplace without a heavy-handed government assault on private businesses. But as yet, it's unclear how the Trump administration will approach the issue of tech monopolies and antitrust law more generally, and to what extent Congress is open to these ideas.

The administration has recently sued to block the merger of AT&T and Time Warner, an aggressive move but one that (ostensibly) relies on age-old antitrust concerns. It's an example of "vertical integration" between two companies that are large but not monopolies: Time Warner owns television networks such as HBO and TNT, while AT&T distributes those networks through products such as DirecTV. In theory, the two combined could benefit from charging AT&T's competitors artificially high rates for Time Warner's content, harming consumers in the process. The other possible rationale is that Trump is merely trying to punish Time Warner, which owns his media archenemy, CNN.

Either way, the suit doesn't provide much of a signal as to how the administration sees Google. But there's certainly a populist angle to keeping a check on enormous companies when no competitors are around to do so — and a conservative angle to ensuring that competition flourishes online.

READ MORE:On Amazon and the Tech MonopoliesSilicon Valley Billionaires Are the New Robber BaronsHow to Break Silicon Valley's Anti-Free-Speech Monopoly

— Robert VerBruggen is a deputy managing editor of National Review.


Source: Google, Facebook, Amazon: Our Digital Overlords

Sunday, December 10, 2017

Take one tablet to cure 20 business problems

Once derided as an oversized iPod or a less functional netbook (remember them?) the tablet has become far more useful and adaptable than both. Today, the tablet is an almost ubiquitous piece of business technology, with as many potential business uses as you can dream up.

Contrary to popular belief, it was Microsoft and Lenovo that partnered to produce the very first tablet PC as far back as 2000, with an improved colour version released two years later sporting the latest Windows XP operating system. However, it was when smarter, app-enabled touchscreen tablets arrived in 2010 that they rapidly became a highly adaptable and effective business and personal device.

Importantly, these new tablets were much thinner and lighter than previous devices. Combined with the app-based functionality popularised by smartphones just a few years earlier, this made them more adaptable, customisable and extremely user friendly.

Tablets may have become a popular consumer device, but these same attributes also made thetablet businessworthy, either as a multi-purpose mobile computer or dedicated to a single and specific business function.

Discover 20 ingenious business tablet uses in our new e-book.

You may have experienced first-hand or seen videos of toddlers and young children able to instinctively use a tablet to play games and access favourite videos with a few finger swipes (or rack up massive app purchase bills if the parents haven't locked their accounts.) But this ease of use also makes a tablet an extremely powerful business tool as well, with many professionals and other active digital users constantly finding ingenious new ways to be more effective and creative with these devices.

From digital restaurant menus that (unlike paper) can be updated in real time, to training health professionals with interactive simulations, we've tracked down 20 different uses for business tablets that demonstrate just how adaptable and powerful these portable black screens can be.

If you're only using your business tablet to update social media or check email, maybe it's time to find out just how powerful it can be when used in conjunction with the right apps and a bit of imagination.


Source: Take one tablet to cure 20 business problems